- 无标题文档
查看论文信息

中文题名:

 中国农村婚嫁彩礼上涨及其效应的经济学分析    

姓名:

 章珂熔    

学号:

 2018206020    

保密级别:

 公开    

论文语种:

 chi    

学科代码:

 120301    

学科名称:

 管理学 - 农林经济管理 - 农业经济管理    

学生类型:

 博士    

学位:

 管理学博士    

学校:

 南京农业大学    

院系:

 经济管理学院    

专业:

 农业经济管理    

研究方向:

 农业经济理论与政策    

第一导师姓名:

 应瑞瑶    

第一导师单位:

 南京农业大学    

第二导师姓名:

 徐志刚    

完成日期:

 2023-12-08    

答辩日期:

 2023-11-30    

外文题名:

 Economic Analysis of Rising Bride Price and Its Effect in Rural China    

中文关键词:

 农村婚嫁彩礼 ; 女性劳动价值 ; 信息不对称 ; 农户生计发展 ; 家庭生育    

外文关键词:

 Rural marriage bride price ; Female’s labor value ; Information asymmetry ; Farmers’ livelihood development ; Family fertility    

中文摘要:

结婚时男方支付彩礼在我国农村是一个普遍现象。彩礼是指夫妻双方订婚和结婚时夫方送予妻方的财货和礼品的统称。我国农村地区彩礼金额自上世纪80年代以来持续攀升,形成高价彩礼现象,尤其是2000年以后彩礼水平快速上升,对中低收入家庭正常生活造成一定压力。我国农村普遍代际责任厚重,父母通常将儿子终身大事看作自己必须要完成的任务,因此高彩礼的压力最终由男方父母来承担。高价彩礼使得许多农村家庭拿出几十年积蓄甚至举债成婚。受传统文化习俗的影响,在相当长的时间内,中国农村仍会存在支付彩礼现象。因此,揭示和明确婚嫁彩礼上涨原因及其影响具有重要的现实意义。

既有研究大多从性别比失衡角度解释彩礼上涨,没有充分揭示我国农村彩礼上涨的深层次原因,单纯从性别比失衡角度不能够完全解释我国彩礼上涨的现象。婚配市场男女供需数量固然重要,但女性劳动力内在价值提升同样不容忽视。现有研究更是主要关注彩礼上涨带来的负面影响,忽略了其对于出生性别比降低可能起到的积极作用。本研究旨在为农村彩礼上涨提供一个新颖且较为完整的思路和分析框架,为今后相关研究提供重要借鉴意义。

本研究的总体目标是:基于代际责任与婚姻效用视角检验农村彩礼上涨对农户生计发展的影响,揭示其作用机制,为乡村治理相关政策的制定提供参考;基于婚姻市场女性劳动价值提升视角分析彩礼上涨对家庭生育的影响及女性家庭决策地位的作用机制,全面客观评价彩礼上涨的综合影响;在劳动力市场发展和面子文化背景下,探讨女性劳动价值提升和信息不对称程度提高对农村彩礼上涨的影响及彩礼要价的示范效应,科学认识农村彩礼上涨的深层次原因。本研究分别采用固定效应模型、随机效应模型、二元选择模型、Tobit模型、面板Tobit模型、Ordered logit模型、OLS模型等进行实证分析。主要研究内容与结论包括三个部分。

第一部分研究农村彩礼上涨对农户生计发展的影响。从家庭负债、教育终止与婚姻稳定三个维度,以男方及其父母为主体分析农村彩礼上涨对农户生计发展的影响机制。利用江苏、四川、吉林3个省297个行政村的四期跟踪调研数据以及1110户农户调查数据进行实证检验。结果表明:在彩礼上涨的背景下,我国农村普遍存在的“传宗接代”的传统文化观念与代际责任使得高彩礼的压力最终由男方父母来承担,结婚时的高彩礼支出确实增加了农户陷入负债的概率并导致负债金额增加。高彩礼的压力还会迫使处于学龄阶段的青年终止学业、提前进入劳动力市场工作,以获得更大的物质资本积累来进行未来彩礼的准备。此外,高彩礼还会给男方带来巨大的生活压力和精神压力,易使他们产生负面情绪,导致夫妻关系紧张,加剧夫妻之间的摩擦和冲突,使得婚姻质量下降,婚姻效用降低,进而影响婚姻稳定性。经验证据表明,伴随着彩礼水平上涨,农村离婚率显著上升。因此彩礼上涨对农户生计发展的影响是多维的,既体现在金融资本(负债)、人力资本(教育)上,也包括对资源(婚姻)发展的影响,而这些又会在一定程度上加剧农户返贫的风险。

第二部分分析农村彩礼上涨对家庭生育的影响。本部分在生育经济动机和家庭决策的框架下,讨论农村彩礼上涨对家庭生育的影响及女性家庭决策地位的作用机制。利用各省市《人口普查资料》和《1%人口抽样调查资料》、中国健康与养老追踪调查(CHARLS)、中国家庭追踪调查(CFPS)、《中国区域经济统计年鉴》多期数据进行实证检验。结果显示:彩礼上涨显著降低出生性别比,这是因为在父母为儿子结婚准备彩礼的背景下,彩礼上涨导致养育男孩的相对成本更高,改变养育子女相对收益,彩礼上涨带来的女性家庭决策地位提升会减弱农村居民在生育各胎次子女时的性别偏好程度,最终通过性别替代机制减少期望男孩数量,从而降低出生性别比。与此同时,彩礼上涨使得养育子女成本更高,这会降低家庭对子女数量的需求,女性家庭决策地位提升也会降低其生育意愿,在高胎次出生性别比失衡更严重的情况下,这会通过生育数量机制间接降低出生性别比。此外,女性家庭决策地位提升以后提供给娘家父母的经济和时间转移支付增加也会提高生育女孩的预期收益,从而弱化男孩偏好,降低出生性别比。由于夫权和男孩偏好程度与宗族文化有关,因而本文进一步根据宗族文化强弱将样本地区分组进行检验,结果表明彩礼上涨对女性家庭决策地位提升和出生性别比降低的作用在宗族文化弱的地区更为显著。

第三部分研究女性劳动价值提升和信息不对称程度提高对农村彩礼上涨的影响及其示范效应。在劳动力市场发展和面子文化背景下,分析女性劳动价值提升(非农劳动参与增加、农业生产率提高)和信息不对称程度提高对农村彩礼上涨的影响以及彩礼要价的示范效应,并利用江苏、四川、吉林3个省297个行政村的四期跟踪调研数据以及1110户农户调查数据进行实证检验。研究发现:首先,女性劳动价值提升显著促进农村彩礼上涨。一方面,大规模的打工经济兴起使得适婚年龄女性非农劳动参与增加,女性对男性的传统依赖下降,女性变得经济独立;另一方面,外包服务的发展改变留在农村从事农业女性的家庭劳动分工参与程度,相应地提升其农业生产率。这两方面的效应均提升女性劳动价值,提高女性在家庭的经济地位,改变婚姻市场上女性作为供给方的价格弹性,进而推动彩礼相应上涨。由于婚姻市场与宗族文化相关,本文进一步检验宗族文化异质性,发现女性劳动价值提升对彩礼上涨的影响在宗族文化强的地区更明显。其次,婚配过程中的信息不对称程度提高会增加女方要高价彩礼进行风险规避的概率,导致彩礼增加,并且这种影响对于中低收入群体更大。最后,示范效应存在于婚嫁彩礼的要价过程中,并且该效应对于中低收入人群更大。

基于上述研究结论,提出如下建议:第一,除了家庭负债等显性问题以外,还需关注因彩礼上涨给农户带来的其他生计问题,如教育终止、婚姻不稳定等隐患。第二,彩礼上涨有其正常合理的部分,对彩礼的引导需要准确识别并因地制宜。第三,彩礼对家庭生育的积极影响值得注意,平衡养育儿子与女儿的收益需从改变生育子女的经济激励入手,制定合理的政策。

本研究可能有以下三方面的创新:

第一,将劳动力市场发展带来的女性劳动价值提升和信息不对称程度提高作为重要的研究视角,运用经济学理论和方法,探究女方彩礼要价的内在机制。现有文献多从社会学角度分析彩礼,彩礼成因涉及文化社会因素,但经济因素也至关重要。本研究从经济学视角揭示经济因素对彩礼变化的影响,从女性劳动参与增加导致劳动力内在价值提升视角出发,充实对于彩礼上涨成因的理解和认知,也为婚姻市场定价理论提供了新的经验证据。以信息不对称和示范效应为切入点,加深对婚姻支付和婚姻市场的认识,并且印证经济因素对文化习俗的影响,拓展相关领域研究。进一步讨论在不同宗族文化地区女性劳动价值提升对彩礼上涨影响的异质性,以及对不同收入水平家庭而言信息不对称程度提高对彩礼的异质性影响和彩礼要价示范效应的异质性,细化并丰富相关研究内容。

第二,将家庭负债、教育终止、婚姻稳定纳入分析框架,综合考察彩礼上涨对农户生计发展的影响与逻辑,深化对返贫成因的理解,为寻找防止农户返贫的有效途径和政策措施提供理论依据与经验证据。区别于已有相关文献对于高额彩礼影响的定性研究,本文运用经济学理论和方法定量分析彩礼上涨对农户生计发展及返贫可能性的影响,研究发现有助于丰富“文化的经济影响”方面文献。为乡村治理相关政策的制定提供参考。

第三,考虑彩礼上涨对家庭生育的积极影响,丰富彩礼上涨综合影响的分析框架。从女性劳动价值提升视角考察彩礼上涨对出生性别比的作用机制,分析女性家庭决策地位对生育决策和转移支付决策的影响,不仅具有重要的现实价值,也对既有文献做出有益补充。本研究结论深化对传统文化习俗与性别平等之间关系的理解,也为关于是否应该禁止彩礼的政策辩论提供一个新的视角。

外文摘要:

It is a common phenomenon that men pay bride price when they get married in rural China. Bride price refers to the general name of goods and gifts given by the husband to the wife when the they are engaged and married. The amount of bride price in rural areas of China has continued to rise since the 1980s, forming the phenomenon of high bride price, especially the rapid rise after 2000, causing a certain pressure on the normal life of middle- and low-income families. In China’s rural areas, there is a heavy intergenerational responsibility, and parents usually regard their son’s life event as a task that they must complete, so the pressure of high bride price is ultimately borne by the parents of the men. High bride price has prompted many rural families to spend decades of savings or even borrow to get married. Due to the influence of traditional culture and customs, the phenomenon of bride price payment will still exist in rural China for a long time. Therefore, it is of great practical significance to reveal and clarify the reasons and influences of the rising bride price.

Most of the existing studies explain the increase of bride price from the angle of sex ratio imbalance, but do not fully reveal the deep-seated reasons for the increase of rural bride price in China, and can not completely explain the phenomenon of rising bride price. Although the number of supply and demand of males and females in the marriage market is important, female’s improvement of the intrinsic value of labor force cannot be ignored. The existing studies mainly focus on the negative effects of bride price increase, ignoring its possible positive effects on the decrease of sex ratio at birth. The purpose of this study is to provide a novel and relatively complete thinking and analysis framework for the rural bride price increase, and to provide important reference for future research.

The overall goal of this study is to examine the impact of rising bride price on the development of farmers’ livelihood and reveal its mechanism based on the perspective of intergenerational responsibility and marital utility, and provides references for the formulation of relevant policies on rural governance. This paper is aimed at analyzing the effect of rising bride price on the family fertility and the mechanism of female’s decision-making status in family, comprehensively and objectively evaluates the comprehensive impact of rising bride price. This paper intends to explore the influence of the improvement of female’s labor value and information asymmetry on the increase of rural bride price as well as the demonstration effect of asking bride price under the background of labor market development and face culture, and scientifically understand the deep-rooted reasons for the rise of rural bride price. In this study, fixed effect model, random effect model, binary selection model, Tobit model, panel Tobit model, Ordered logit model and OLS model were used for empirical analysis. The main research contents and conclusions include three parts.

The first part studies the impact of rising bride price on the development of farmers’ livelihood. From the three dimensions of family debt, education termination and marital stability, this paper analyzes the influence mechanism of rising bride price on the development of farmers’ livelihood by taking males and their parents as the main body. This paper empirically tests the impact based on the four phase tracking data of 297 administrative villages in Jiangsu, Sichuan and Jilin provinces and the survey data of 1110 rural households. The results show that under the background of the rising bride price, the traditional cultural concept of “carrying on the family name” and intergenerational responsibility in rural China make the pressure of high bride price finally borne by the male’s parents. The high bride price expenditure at the time of marriage does increase the probability of farmers falling into debt and lead to an increase in the amount of debt. Under the pressure of high bride price, it also forces school-age teenager to terminate their studies and enter the labor market earlier in order to accumulate greater material capital to prepare for future bride price. In addition, high bride price will also bring tremendous life pressure and mental pressure to the men, which is easy to make them have negative emotions, leading to tension between husband and wife, aggravating friction and conflict between them, resulting in the decline of marriage quality and marriage effectiveness, and thus affecting the stability of marriage. Empirical evidence shows that the divorce rate in rural areas increases significantly with the increase in bride price. Therefore, the impact of bride price increase on the development of farmers’ livelihood is multi-dimensional, which is reflected in financial capital (debt), human capital (education), and the development of resources (marriage), which will aggravate the risk of farmers returning to poverty to a certain extent.

The second part studies the effect of rising bride price on family fertility. Under the framework of economic motivation and family decision making, this paper analyzes the effect of rising bride price on the decrease of sex ratio at birth and the mechanism of female’s family decision making status. The empirical test is conducted by using the multiphase data of Population Census, 1% Population Sample Survey, China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Study (CHARLS), China Family Panel Studies (CFPS), and China Regional Economic Statistical Yearbook. The results show that rising bride price significantly reduces the sex ratio at birth because it leads to higher relative costs of raising boys in the context of parents preparing bride price for their sons’ marriages and changes the relative benefits of raising children. The improvement of female’s decision-making status in family due to the rising bride price will weaken the gender preference of rural residents when giving birth to children, and ultimately reduce the desired number of boys through gender substitution mechanism, thereby reducing the sex ratio at birth. At the same time, the rising bride price makes the cost of raising children higher, which will reduce the family’s demand for the number of children, and the improvement of female’s decision-making status in the family will also reduce their fertility willingness, which will indirectly reduce the sex ratio at birth through the birth number mechanism in the case of the imbalance of the sex ratio at high birth parity. In addition, the increase in economic and time transfer payments provided to parents after female’s decision-making status in the family will also increase the expected benefits of having girls, thus weakening the preference for boys and reducing the sex ratio at birth. Since husband power and boy preference are related to clan culture, this paper further tests the sample regions according to the strength of clan culture. The results show that the effect of bride price increase on female’s decision-making status and sex ratio at birth is more significant in the regions with weak clan culture.

The third part studies the influence of female’s labor value and the increase in information asymmetry on the rise of rural bride price and its demonstration effect. In the context of labor market development and face culture, this paper analyzes the influence of female’s labor value (increase in non-agricultural labor participation, increase in agricultural productivity) and the increase in information asymmetry on the rise of rural bride price as well as the demonstration effect of asking bride price, and uses the four phase tracking survey data of 297 administrative villages in Jiangsu, Sichuan and Jilin provinces and the survey data of 1110 rural households for empirical test. The study finds that, first of all, the rise of female’s labor value significantly promotes the increase of rural bride prices. On the one hand, the rise of large-scale working economy makes the non-agricultural labor participation of females at marriageable age increase, females’ traditional dependence on males declines, and they become economically independent. On the other hand, the development of outsourcing services has changed the degree of participation in the household division of labor of females who remain in rural areas to work in agriculture, and correspondingly increased their agricultural productivity. Both of these effects improve female’s labor value and their economic status in the family, change the price elasticity of females as suppliers in the marriage market, which in turn drives up bride prices accordingly. Since the marriage market is related to clan culture, this paper further examines the heterogeneity of clan culture and finds that the influence of the increase of female’s labor value on the rise of bride price is more obvious in areas with strong clan culture. Secondly, the increase of information asymmetry in the process of marriage will increase the probability of females wanting high price for risk avoidance, resulting in an increase in bride price. And this impact is greater for middle- and low- income groups. Finally, the demonstration effect exists in the process of asking bride price, and the effect is larger for middle- and low- income people.

Based on the above research conclusions, the following suggestions are put forward: First, in addition to the obvious problems such as household debt, other livelihood problems brought by the rising bride price to farmers should also be paid attention to, such as education termination, marital instability and other hidden dangers. Second, the rising of bride price has its normal and reasonable parts, and the guidance of bride price needs to be accurately identified and adapted to local conditions. Third, the positive impact of bride price on family fertility is noteworthy. To balance the benefits of raising sons and daughters, it is necessary to change the economic incentives to have children and formulate reasonable policies.

This research may be innovative in the following three aspects:

First, take the rise of female’s labor value and the increase of information asymmetry brought about by the development of labor market as an important research perspective, and use economic theories and methods to explore the internal mechanism of female’s bride price asking. The existing literature mostly analyzes the bride price from the sociological angle. The causes of bride price involve cultural and social factors, but economic factors are also crucial. From the perspective of economics, this study reveals the influence of economic factors on the change of bride price, and from the perspective of the increase of female’s labor force participation leading to the improvement of labor’s intrinsic value, enriching the understanding and cognition of the causes of the rise of bride price, and providing new empirical evidence for the theory of marriage market pricing. Taking the information asymmetry and demonstration effect as the entry point, it deepens the understanding of marriage payment and marriage market, confirms the influence of economic factors on cultural customs, and expands the research in related fields. This paper further discusses the heterogeneity of the influence of female’s labor value on the increase of bride price in different clan cultural regions, the heterogeneity of information asymmetry on bride price, and the demonstration effect of bride price asking for families with different income levels, elaborating and enriching the relevant research contents.

Second, family debt, education termination and marriage stability are included in the analysis framework, and the impact and logic of rising bride price on the development of farmers’ livelihoods are comprehensively investigated, so as to deepen the understanding of the causes of poverty return, and provide theoretical basis and empirical evidence for finding effective ways and policy measures to prevent farmers from returning to poverty. Different from the qualitative research on the impact of high bride price in the existing literature, this paper uses economic theories and methods to quantitatively analyze the impact of rising bride price on the development of farmers’ livelihoods and the possibility of returning to poverty. The research findings are helpful to enrich the literature on the “economic impact of culture”. It provides reference for the formulation of relevant policies of rural governance.

Third, consider the positive impact of rising bride price on family fertility, and enrich the analysis framework of the comprehensive impact of rising bride price. From the perspective of female’s labor value improvement, it is not only of practical value, but also helpful to supplement existing literature to investigate the mechanism of bride price increase on birth sex ratio and analyze the influence of female’s family decision-making status on fertility decision and transfer payment decision. The conclusions of this study deepen the understanding of the relationship between traditional cultural practices and gender equality, and also provide a new perspective on the policy debate on whether bride price should be banned.

参考文献:

[1] Akerlof, G. The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism[J].Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1970 (84):488-500.

[2] Alesina, A., P. Giuliano, and N. Nunn. On the Origins of Gender Roles: Women and the Plough[J]. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2013, 128 (2):469-530.

[3] Almond, D., Li, H., and Zhang, S. Land Reform and Sex Selection in China. Journal of Political Economy, 2019,127(2): 560-585.

[4] Anderson, S. The Economics of Dowry and Brideprice[J]. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2007, 21(4): 151-174.

[5] Anderson, D., and S. Hamori. A theory of quality signaling in the marriage market[J].Japan and the World Economy, 2000.

[6] Angrist, J. How Do Sex Ratios Affect Marriage and Labor Markets? Evidence from America’s Second Generation[J]. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2002,117(3):997-1038.

[7] Anukriti, S., Kwon, S., Prakash, N. Saving for Dowry: Evidence from Rural India[J]. Journal of Development Economics, 2022, 154, 102750.

[8] Ashraf N. Spousal Control and Intra-Household Decision Making: An Experimental Study in the Philippines[J]. American Economic Review, 2009(99):1245-77.

[9] Ashraf, N., N. Bau, N. Nunn, and A. Voena. Bride Price and Female Education[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 2020, 128 (2): 591–641.

[10] Banister, J. Shortage of Girls in China Today[J]. Journal of Population Research, 2004, 21(1), 19-45.

[11] Becker, G. S. “An Economic Analysis of Fertility”, in Universities-National Bureau (eds.), Demographic and Change in Developed Countries[M]. New York: Columbia University Press, 1960.

[12] Becker, G. S. A Treatise on the Family [M]. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1991.

[13] Bélanger, D. and Linh, T. G. The Impact of Transnational Migration on Gender and Marriage in Sending Communities of Vietnam[J]. Current Sociology, 2011,59(1),59-77.

[14] Bhattacharjya D, Sudarshan A, Tuljapurkar S, et al. How Can Economic Schemes Curtail the Increasing Sex Ratio at Birth in China?[J]. Demographic research, 2008, 19(54): 1831.

[15] Boserup, E. Women’s Role in Economic Development[M]. London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd,1970.

[16] Chambers R, Conway G. Sustainable Rural Livelihoods: Practical Concepts for the 21st Century, IDS Discussion Paper 296. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies, 1992.

[17] Chen and Zhang. Imbalance in China’s Sex Ratio at Birth: A Review[J]. Journal of Economic Surveys,2019, 33(3): 1050–1069.

[18] Chen, Y., Li, H., and Meng, L. Prenatal Sex Selection and Missing Girls in China: Evidence from the Diffusion of Diagnostic Ultrasound. Journal of Human Resources, 2013, 48(1): 36-70.

[19] Chen, Z., Ma, C., and Sinclair, A. J. Banking on the Confucian Clan: Why China Developed Financial Markets So Late. The Economic Journal, 2022, 132(644): 1378-1413.

[20] Cherlin, A. The Effect of Children on Marital Dissolution [J]. Demography,1977(3):265-272.

[21] Clark, S. Son Preference and Sex Composition of Children: Evidence from India. Demography 2000,37:95-108.

[22] Coale, A., J. Excess Female Mortality and the Balance of the Sexes in the Population: An Estimate of the Number of ‘Missing Females’[J]. Population and Development Review 1991,17(3):517-523.

[23] Cohen M. House United, House Divided: The Chinese Family In Taiwan[M]. New York: Columbia University Press, 1976.

[24] Coltrance, S. Family Man: Fatherhood, Housework and Gender Equity[M]. New York: Oxford Universiy Press, 1996: 293- 304.

[25] Corno, L., N. Hildebrandt, and A. Voena. Age of Marriage, Weather Shocks, and the Direction of Marriage Payments[J]. Econometrica, 2020, 88 (3): 879–915.

[26] Corno, L., Voena, A. Child Marriage as Informal Insurance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Simulations[J]. Journal of Development Economics, 2023, 162, 103047.

[27] Das Gupta, M., Z. Jiang, B. Li, Z. Xie, W. Chung, and B. Hwa-OK. Why is Son Preference So Persistent in East and South Asia? A Cross-Country Study of China, India and the Republic of Korea[J]. Journal of Development Studies, 2003, 40(2):153-187.

[28] Conway, D., Schipper, E. Lisa F. Adaptation to Climate Change in Africa: Challenges and Opportunities Identified from Ethiopia[J]. Global Environmental Change, 2011,21(1): 227-237.

[29] Dong Z, Alhaj-Yaseen Y, Jiao Y, Zhong Y. Surplus Men and Scarce Women: The impact of Mating Competition on the Desire for Sons in China. Pac Econ Rev[J]. 2021, 26:339–371.

[30] Du J., Wang Y., Zhang Y. Sex Imbalance, Marital Matching and Intra-Household Bargaining: Evidence from China[J]. China Economic Review, 2015,35(4):197-218.

[31] Duesenberry J. S. Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior[M]. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1949.

[32] Ebenstein, A.Y. Patrilocality and Missing Women. 2014. Available at SSRN: https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2422090

[33] Ebenstein, A., and Leung S. Son Preference and Access to Social Insurance: Evidence from China’s Rural Pension Program[J]. Population and Development Review,2010,36(1):47-80.

[34] Ehrlich, I., and F. T. Lui. Intergenerational Trade, Longevity, and Economic Growth[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 1991,99(5):1029-1059.

[35] Ellis, Frank, Edward H Allison. The Livelihoods Approach and Management of Small-scale Fisheries[J]. Marine Policy, 2001,25(5): 377-388.

[36] Engel, J., W. Marriage in the People’s Republic of China: Analysis of a New Law[J]. Journal of Marriage and the Family,1984,46(4):955-961.

[37] Feldman, M. W., Tuljapurkar, S., Li, S., Jin, X., and Li, N. (2006). Son Preference, Marriage, and Intergenerational Transfer in Rural China. In: Gauthier, A. H., Chu, C. Y. C., and Tuljapurkar, S. (eds.) Population, Resources and Development, volume 2: Allocating Public and Private Resources across Generations: Riding the Age Waves, pp.139–162. Dordrecht: Springer. (International studies in population; 3).

[38] Festini, F., & Martino, M. de. Twenty Five Years of the one Child Family Policy in China. Journal of Epidemiology & Community Health, 2004, 58(5): 358-360.

[39] Francis, A. Sex Ratios and the Red Dragon: Using the Chinese Communist Revolution to Explore the Effect of the Sex Ratio on Women and Children in Taiwan[J]. Journal of Population Economics, 2011,24(3): 813-837.

[40] Freedman, M. Chinese Lineage and Society: Fukien and Kwangtung [M]. London: London Athlone Press, 1966.

[41] Godwin, D., John, S. Couple Consensus during Marital Joint Decision-Making: A Context, Process, Outcome Model[J]. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 1989, 51(4):943-956.

[42] Greif, A. and Tabellini, G. The Clan and the Corporation: Sustaining Cooperation in China and Europe[J]. Journal of Comparative Economics, 2017, 45(1):1-35.

[43] Guilmoto, C. Z., and Tove, J. The Masculinization of Births. Overview and Current Knowledge[J]. Population, 2015, 70(2): 185-243.

[44] Hague, G., R. K. Thiara, and A. Turner. Bride-Price and Its Links to Domestic Violence and Poverty in Uganda: A Participatory Action Research Study[J]. Women’s Studies International Forum, 2011, 34 (6): 550–561.

[45] Harrell, S. Patriliny, Patriarchy, Patrimony Surface Features and Deep Structures in the Chinese Family System. Retrieved from http: //faculty.Washington.edu/stevehar/PPP. Html, 2002.

[46] Hesketh, T. The Effect of China's One-child Family Policy after 25 Years[J]. New England Journal of Medicine, 2005, 353:1171.

[47] Hiwatari, M. Social Networks and Migration Decisions: The Influence of Peer Effects in Rural Households in Central Asia[J]. Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 2016, 44(4): 1115–1131.

[48] Hoppe, H. C., Moldovanu, B., and Sela A. The Theory of Assortative Matching Based on Costly Signals[J]. Review of Economic Studies, 2009, 76: 253–281.

[49] Hotte, R., Lambert S. Marriage Payments and Wives’ Welfare: All You Need is Love[J]. Journal of Development Economics, 2023, 164, 103141.

[50] Jiang, Q., Sánchez-Barricarte, Jesús J. Bride Price in China: the Obstacle to ‘Bare Branches’ Seeking Marriage[J]. History of the Family, 2012, 17(1):2-15.

[51] Kerr, A. A Shortage of Brides: China’s One Child Policy and Transitions of Men into Marriage[J]. Research in Economics, 2023, 77: 310–321.

[52] Kojo, O. J., Seidu, Abdul-Aziz, Ameyaw, E. K., et al. Bride Price Payment and Justification of Sexual Violence Among Women in Ghana[J]. Journal of Interpersonal Violence, 2022, 37 (9-10): NP6284-NP6300.

[53] Komter, A. 1989, Hidden Power in Marriage[J]. Gender & Society, 3(2): 187-216.

[54] Kaye, D. K., Mirembe, F., Ekstrom, A. M., et al. Implications of Bride Price on Domestic Violence and Reproductive Health in Wakiso District, Uganda[J].African Health Sciences, 2005, 5(4):300-303.

[55] Li L., Wu X. Gender of Children, Bargaining Power, and Intrahousehold Resource Allocation in China[J]. The Journal of Human Resources, 2011,46(2):295-316.

[56] Li, S., M. Feldman, and X. Jin. Children, Marriage Form and Family Support for Elderly in Contemporary Rural China[J]. Research on Aging, 2004,26(3):352-384.

[57] Mcdonald, G., W. Family Power: The Assessment of a Decade of Theory and Research, 1970-1979[J]. Journal of Marriage and Family, 1980, 42(4):841-854.

[58] Mcdonald, G. W. Family Power: Reflection and Direction[J]. Pacific Sociological Review, 1977, 20(4): 607-621.

[59] McDonald, P. Gender Equity in Theories of Fertility Transition[J]. Population and development review, 2000, 26(3), 427-439.

[60] Mansoor, N. Marriage Payments and Women’s Bargaining Power in Rural Bangladesh[J]. Journal of Demographic Economics, 2018, 84 (1): 79–105.

[61] Oster, E. Hepatitis B and the Case of the Missing Women[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 2005, 113 (6):1163-216.

[62] Piccoli L. Female Poverty and Intrahousehold Inequality in Transition Economies[EB/OL]. http://wol.iza.org/uploads/articles/353/pdfs/female-poverty-and-intrahousehold-inequality-in-transition economies. pdf,2017.

[63] Poston Jr, D. L., Gu, B., Liu, P. P., and McDaniel, T. Son Preference and the Sex Ratio at Birth in China: A Provincial Level Analysis. Social biology, 1997, 44(1-2), 55-76.

[64] Potter H. S. and Potter J. M. China’s Peasants: The Anthropology of a Revolution [M]. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,1990.

[65] Qian, N. Missing Women and the Price of Tea in China: The Effect of Sex-specific Earnings on Sex Imbalance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2008, 123(3), 1251-1285.

[66] Razavi, S. Gendered Poverty and Well-being. Blackwell Publishers, 2000.

[67] Rees, Susan, Mohammed Mohsin, Alvin Kuowei Tay, Rosamund Thorpe, Samantha Murray, Elisa Savio, Mira Fonseca, Wietse Tol, and Derrick Silove. Associations between Bride Price Obligations and Women’s Anger, Symptoms of Mental Distress, Poverty, Spouse and Family Conflict and Preoccupations with Injustice in Conflict-Affected Timor-Leste[J]. BMJ Global Health, 2016, 1 (1): e000025.

[68] Robert Chambers, Editorial: Responsible Well-being - A Personal Agenda for Development[J]. World Development,1997,25(11): 1743-1754.

[69] Ross, C. E. The Division of Labor at Home. Social forces[J]. 1987, 65(3), 816-833.

[70] Rothschild, S., J. Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Market[J]. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1976 (90) :629-649.

[71] Salafsky, E., W. Linking Livelihoods and Conservation: A Conceptual Framework and Scale for Assessing the Integration of Human Needs and Biodiversity[J]. World Development, 2000,28(8): 1421-1438.

[72] Scoones, C., T. Soil Nutrient Balances: What Use for Policy? [J]. Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment, 1998,71(1-3): 255-267.

[73] Singh, D. and Goli, S. Familial Power Relations, Popularity of Female Sterilization, Sertility Decline in Rural Andhra Pradesh: A Cultural Understanding, pp. 107-126 in edited Alok Ranjan ‘Contemporary issues in fertility and family planning in India’, Indo-American Publications, New Delhi.;ISBN: 81-902592, 2010.

[74] Song, S. Does Famine Have a Long-Term Effect on Cohort Mortality? Evidence from the 1959-1961 Great Leap Forward Famine in China[J]. Journal of Biosocial Science,2009,41(4):469-91.

[75] Spence, A.M. Job Market Signling[J].Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1973 (87) :355-374.

[76] Spence, A.M. Market Signaling: The Informational Structure of Job Markets and Related Phenomena[M].New York: Harvard University Press, 1974.

[77] Stopnitzky Y. No Toilet No Bride? Intrahousehold Bargaining in Male-Skewed Marriage Markets in India[J]. Journal of Development Economics, 2017(127):269-82.

[78] Sun, A., and Zhao, Y. Divorce, Abortion, and the Child Sex Ratio: The Impact of Divorce Reform in China. Journal of Development Economics, 2016, 120: 53-69.

[79] Ted, A., T. Covariates of Men’s Age at First Marriage: The Historical Demography of Chinese Lineages [J]. Population Studies, 1992,46(1):19-35.

[80] Xu, Z., Zhang, K., Zhou, L. and Ying, R. Mutual Proximity and Heterogeneity in Peer Effects of Farmers’ Technology Adoption: Evidence from China’s Soil Testing and Formulated Fertilization Program[J]. China Agricultural Economic Review, 2022, 14(2): 395-415.

[81] Xue, M., M. High-Value Work and the Rise of Women: The Cotton Revolution and Gender Equality in China[M].MPRA Paper No. 91100,2018.

[82] Zeng, Y., P. Tu, B. Gu, Y. Xu, B. Li, and Y. Li. Causes and Implications of the Recent Increase in the Reported Sex Ratio at Birth in China[J]. Population and Development Review,1993,19(2):283-302.

[83] Zhang, Z., and Zhao, Z. Women’s Education and Fertility in China. China Economic Review, 2023, 78, 101936.

[84] Zhu, W., Lu, L., and Hesketh, T. China’s Excess Males, Sex Selective Abortion, and One Child Policy: Analysis of Data from 2005 National Intercensus Survey. BMJ, 2009, 338: 920–923.

[85] 白仲林,杨萍,赵蓉.生命不确定性的跨期最优消费行为研究[J].统计研究,2012(2):28-33.

[86] 贝克尔著,王献生,王宇译,家庭论[M].北京:商务印书馆,2011.

[87] 陈晶环.天价彩礼何以可能:一种基于劳动激励与消费机制的建构论阐释[J].华中农业大学学报(社会科学版),2022(02):123-130.

[88] 陈克进.婚姻家庭词典[M].中国国际广播出版社,1989.

[89] 陈强.高级计量经济学及Stata应用(第二版)[M].北京:高等教育出版社,2014.

[90] 陈秋盼,王海平,康丽颖.家庭帮衬:农村青年婚姻中高额彩礼的形成机制分析[J].当代青年研究,2018(05):48-53.

[91] 陈文江,王雄刚.从“礼俗”到“市场”:高价彩礼的生成机制——基于陇东南X村的考察[J].甘肃社会科学,2021(05):16-24.

[92] 陈印陶.打工妹的婚恋观念及其困扰——来自广东省的调查报告[J].人口研究,1997(02):39-44.

[93] 翟学伟.人情、面子与权力的再生产——情理社会中的社会交换方式[J].社会学研究,2004(05):48-57.

[94] 刁统菊.嫁妆与聘礼:一个学术史的简单回顾[J].山东大学学报(哲学社会科学版),2007,(02):155-160.

[95] 刁统菊.离心力:姻亲关系之于家庭组织的一种影响[J].民俗研究,2007(02):24-37.

[96] 段新星,王秋月.青年婚姻市场中的彩礼定价——以南方G县城的婚姻市场为例[J].中国青年研究,2016,(9):29-37.

[97] 法律出版社编写组.中华人民共和国婚姻法[M].北京:法律出版社,2011.

[98] [法]布迪厄著, 姜志辉译. 单身者舞会[M]..上海:上海译文出版社,2009.

[99] 范子英,顾晓敏.性别比失衡的再平衡:来自“关爱女孩行动”的证据[J].经济学动态,2017(04):77-89.

[100] 费孝通.乡土中国[M]. 北京: 三联书店, 1985.

[101] [芬兰]韦斯特马克.人类婚姻史(1-3卷)[M].北京:商务印书馆,2002.

[102] 龚晓珺.试析青年农民“因婚返贫”的非正式制度致因及其整体协同治理策略[J].中国青年研究,2018(03):71-78.

[103] 古德著,魏章玲译.家庭[M]. 北京:社会科学文献出版社,1986.

[104] 桂华,余练.婚姻市场要价:理解农村婚姻交换现象的一个框架[J].青年研究,2010(03):24-36+94-95.

[105] 郭志刚,邓国胜.婚姻市场理论研究—兼论中国生育率下降过程中的婚姻市场[J].中国人口科学,1995(3):11-16.

[106] 何倩倩.农村彩礼变动的两重分析:婚配性别比结构与代际责任[J].华中农业大学学报(社会科学版),2021(02):120-127+181.

[107] 贺飞.转型期青年农民工婚恋观念和行为的社会学分析[J].青年研究,2007(04):42-49.

[108] 侯双. 生计资本、外部环境与扶贫移民生计发展[D].华中师范大学,2016.

[109] 黄国华,刘传江,涂海丽.中国出生性别比时空特征及影响因素[J].江西社会科学,2018,38(02):225-234+256.

[110] 黄江玉. 基于可持续生计视角的PPP模式减贫效应研究[D].中央财经大学,2019.

[111] 霍宏伟.我国北方一个农庄的婚姻圈研究——对山东省济阳县江店乡贾寨村的个案分析[J].社会,2002(12):36-40.

[112] 吉国秀.婚姻支付的变迁:一个姻亲关系的视角[J].民间文化论坛, 2006(1):17-21.

[113] 冀东星.女性农业生产率与婚姻转移支付[J].经济学(季刊),2020,19(02):567-590.

[114] 姜彩芬.面子文化产生根源及社会功能[J].广西社会科学,2009(03):116-120.

[115] 金一虹.流动的父权:流动农民家庭的变迁[J].中国社会科学,2010(04):151-165+223.

[116] 靳小怡,段朱清.天价彩礼源何来:城镇化下的中国农村男性婚姻成本研究[J].妇女研究论丛,2019,(06):18-31.

[117] 康传坤,文强,楚天舒.房子还是儿子?——房价与出生性别比[J].经济学(季刊),2020,19(03):913-934.

[118] 冷遥,雷明光.少数民族农村地区离婚现状与思考[J].贵州民族研究,2019,40(07):84-94.

[119] 李洪祥.彩礼返还之规定的社会性别分析[J].法学杂志,2005(02):81-83.

[120] 李军,李敬.代际剥削?彩礼习俗与农村父母健康 [J].人口与发展,2023,29 (01):137-148+136.

[121] 李敏,张利明.当前农村不良社会风气的态势、成因及对策——基于全国200多个村4000多家农户连续3年的调查[J].西北农林科技大学学报(社会科学版),2018(2):94-100+114.

[122] 李强.同伴效应对农村义务教育儿童辍学的影响[J].教育与经济,2019(4):36-44.

[123] 李树茁,姜全保,刘慧君.性别歧视的人口后果——基于公共政策视角的模拟分析[J].公共管理学报,2006,(2):90-98,112.

[124] 李树茁,姜全保,伊莎贝尔•阿塔尼,等.中国的男孩偏好和婚姻挤压——初婚与再婚市场的综合分析[J].人口与经济,2006,(4):1-8.

[125] 李树茁.性别失衡、男性婚姻挤压与婚姻策略[J].探索与争鸣,2013,(05):22-23.

[126] 李文.中国农村妇女经济地位实证研究——以江苏省和甘肃省为例[J].农业经济问题,2009(04):26-32+110-111.

[127] 李霞.民间习俗中的彩礼及其流变[J].民俗研究,2008(03):253-262.

[128] 李霞.依附者还是构建者?——关于妇女亲属关系的一项民族志研究[J].思想战线,2005(01):82-87.

[129] 李潇晓,徐水晶.外出务工对农村人口婚姻满意度的影响[J].华南农业大学学报(社会科学版), 2018,17(06):114-125.

[130] 李永萍.归属视角下农村低额彩礼形成的动力机制——基于赣南G村的田野调查[J].北京社会科学,2022(01):120-128.

[131] 李永萍.联合家庭再生产模式:理解低额彩礼的一种视角——基于粤北宗族性村庄的考察[J].当代青年研究,2018(03):96-102.

[132] 李雨潼,杨竹.东北地区离婚率特征分析及原因思考[J].人口学刊,2011(3):47-52.

[133] 李中清,王丰著; 陈卫,姚远译.人类的四分之一:马尔萨斯的神话与中国的现实(1700-2000)[M].上海:三联书店,2000.

[134] 李仲武,冯学良.女性家庭地位越高就越幸福吗?[J].统计研究,2021,38(10):121-133.

[135] 栗志强.农村男方婚姻支付:性别比失衡背景下的农民婚姻策略[D].上海大学,2012.

[136] 林胜,黄静雅.农村天价彩礼对青年女性的负面影响——以莆田某村为例[J].中国青年研究,2019(02):73-79.

[137] 刘彬彬,崔菲菲,史清华.劳动力流动与村庄离婚率[J].中国农村经济,2018(10):71-92.

[138] 刘成良.因婚致贫:理解农村贫困的一个视角[J].南京农业大学学报(社会科学版),2018,18(03):37-44+153.

[139] 刘凡熙.从代际关系角度看当前中国农村高额彩礼问题——基于黑龙江M村的调查研究[J].学术交流,2018(01):130-137.

[140] 刘倩.打工妹:在婚姻与家庭中向平等迈进[J].妇女研究论丛,1998(03):24-27.

[141] 刘汶蓉,李冰洁.“过家人难”:农村青年的婚姻风险化与个体策略困境——基于豫西南D县的调查研究[J].妇女研究论丛,2021(2):84-96.

[142] 刘燕舞.负性生命事件、地域性贫困与农村光棍问题的形成机制研究——以大别山村为个案[J].贵州社会科学,2019(10):149-158.

[143] 刘燕舞.农村光棍的类型研究——一种人口社会学的分析[J].中国农业大学学报(社会科学版),2011,28(03):160-169.

[144] 刘银双. 地理位置与现金股利[D].江西财经大学,2020.

[145] 柳清瑞,刘淑娜.高价彩礼对农村家庭消费的挤出效应——基于扩展OLG模型的实证检验[J].人口与经济,2020,(05):87-102.

[146] 马忠才,郝苏民.乡村教育振兴的困境及其内生性逻辑——基于深度贫困地区Y县的调查分析[J].中南民族大学学报(人文社会科学版),2020(2):169-174.

[147] [美]弗雷格斯坦著, 甄志宏译.市场的结构[M].上海:上海人民出版社,2008.

[148] [美]曼昆著;梁小民,梁砾译.经济学原理:第6版. 微观经济学分册[M].北京:北京大学出版社,2012.

[149] [美]乔纳森·特纳著,邱泽奇译.社会学理论的结构[M].北京:华夏出版社,2001.

[150] 纳玉兰.河湟农村高额“彩礼”探析——以青海省峡口村为例[J].青海民族研究, 2015, 26(01): 67-70.

[151] 邱海兰,唐超.农业生产性服务能否促进农民收入增长[J].广东财经大学学报,2019,(5):100-112.

[152] 邱泽奇,丁浩.农村婚嫁流动[J].社会学研究,1991(03):62-66.

[153] 任强,郑维东.我国婚姻市场挤压的决定因素[J].人口学刊,1998,(05):24-30.

[154] 沙吉才. 当代中国妇女家庭地位研究[M]. 天津:天津人民出版社,1995.

[155] 尚婷婷.东北虎豹国家公园居民可持续生计发展水平评价与对策研究[D].东北林业大学,2020.

[156] 石人炳.青年人口迁出对农村婚姻的影响[J].人口学刊,2006,(01):32-36.

[157] 苏群,徐月娥,陈杰.父母外出务工与留守子女辍学——基于CHNS调查数据的经验分析[J].教育与经济,2015(2):67-72.

[158] 谭仁杰.市场经济与婚姻发展趋势[J].经济评论,1995(01):82-87.

[159] 陶涛.中国农村妇女家庭重大决策参与权的影响因素研究[J].妇女研究论丛,2012(05):17-22+35.

[160] 陶自祥.高额彩礼:理解农村代内剥削现象的一种视角——性别视角下农村女性早婚的思考[J].民俗研究,2011(03):259-269.

[161] 王会.集体经济模式下苏南农村妇女地位研究——兼与浙北农村妇女地位比较[J].中国青年研究, 2016,(12):27-32.

[162] 王敬.低额彩礼习俗维系机制的多维度分析——基于广州市F村的驻村调查[J].中国青年研究,2021(04):91-97.

[163] 王敬,海莉娟.婚姻市场分层化与公共仪式市场化——陕西关中地区农村青年婚嫁的运作机制[J].中国青年研究,2018(06):53-58+111.

[164] 王群勇,赵玮.美貌与权利——来自中国家庭的微观证据[J].南开经济研究,2019(06):181-198+218.

[165] 王沙沙.转型时期农村彩礼现象的社会学分析[D].东北师范大学,2011.

[166] 王向阳.当前我国农村“天价彩礼”的产生机制及其治理[J].西南大学学报(社会科学版),2021,47(05):37-46+223-224.

[167] 王晓慧,刘燕舞.农村大龄青年婚配困难问题研究——社会剥夺的视角[J].中国农村观察,2017(02):117-129.

[168] 王跃生.婚事操办中的代际关系:家庭财产积累与转移——冀东农村的考察[J].中国农村观察,2010,(03):60-72.

[169] 韦艳,姜全保.代内剥削与代际剥削?——基于九省百村调查的中国农村彩礼研究[J].人口与经济,2017(05):57-69.

[170] 魏国学,熊启泉,谢玲红.转型期的中国农村人口高彩礼婚姻——基于经济学视角的研究[J].中国人口科学,2008,(04):30-36+95.

[171] 温蓉. 农村城市化进程中女性家庭地位实证研究[D].西北民族大学,2007.

[172] 温莹莹.非正式制度与村庄公共物品供给—T村个案研究[J].社会学研究,2013(1):113-133.

[173] 吴晓瑜,李力行.母以子贵:性别偏好与妇女的家庭地位——来自中国营养健康调查的证据[J].经济学(季刊),2011,10(03):869-886.

[174] 吴重庆.社会变迁与通婚地域的伸缩——莆田孙村“通婚地域”调查[J].开放时代,1999(04):71-81.

[175] 新山.婚嫁格局变动与乡村发展——以康村通婚圈为例[J].人口学刊,2000(01):32-36.

[176] 邢春冰,聂海峰.城里小伙儿遇到农村姑娘:婴儿户口、户籍改革与跨户籍通婚[J].世界经济文汇,2010,(4):1-18.

[177] 熊凤水.婚姻支付研究[D].华中师范大学,2008.

[178] 徐安琪.夫妻权力和妇女家庭地位的评价指标:反思与检讨[J].社会学研究,2005(04):134-152+245.

[179] 徐安琪.择偶标准:五十年变迁及其原因分析[J].社会学研究,2000(06):18-30.

[180] 徐戈,陆迁,姜雅莉.社会资本、收入多样化与农户贫困脆弱性[J].中国人口•资源与环境,2019(2):123-133.

[181] 许庆,陆钰凤,张恒春.农业支持保护补贴促进规模农户种粮了吗?——基于全国农村固定观察点调查数据的分析[J].中国农村经济,2020(04):15-33.

[182] 徐志刚,谭鑫,郑旭媛,等.农地流转市场发育对粮食生产的影响与约束条件[J].中国农村经济,2017,(9):26-43.

[183] 徐志刚,章珂熔,彭澎.乡村公共空间治理:江苏实践与理论诠释[J].农业经济问题,2023(01):64-75.

[184] 阎云翔.礼物的流动:一个中国村庄的互惠原则与社会网络[M].上海:上海人民出版社,2000.

[185] 杨华.代际责任、通婚圈与农村“天价彩礼”——对农村彩礼机制的理解[J].北京社会科学,2019(03):91-100.

[186] 杨华.农村婚姻市场中的结构性因素—基于湘南水村“光棍汉”的调查[J].江西师范大学学报,2008(2):7-9.

[187] 杨旭东.新时期农村移风易俗的历史观照与现实思考[J].中州学刊,2019(11):78-84.

[188] 姚东旻,许艺煊,张鹏远.灾难经历、时间偏好与家庭储蓄行为[J].世界经济,2019(1):145-169.

[189] 叶文振,林擎国.中国大龄未婚人口现象存在的原因及对策分析[J].中国人口科学,1998(04):17-23.

[190] 殷浩栋,毋亚男,汪三贵,王瑜,王姮.“母凭子贵”:子女性别对贫困地区农村妇女家庭决策权的影响[J].中国农村经济,2018,(01):108-123.

[191] 尹旦萍.当代土家族女性的婚姻变迁——以埃山村为例[M].北京:社会科学文献出版社,2009.

[192] 应瑞瑶,徐斌.农户采纳农业社会化服务的示范效应分析——以病虫害统防统治为例[J].中国农村经济,2014,(08):30-41.

[193] 余练.婚姻连带:理解农村光棍现象的一个新视角——对鄂中和鄂东三村光棍成窝现象的解释[J].人口与经济,2017(01):13-21.

[194] 余练.农民分化与通婚圈结构变迁——基于皖中大鼓村婚姻市场的考察[J].华中科技大学学报(社会科学版),2013,27(01):114-121.

[195] 袁梦,郑筱婷.父母外出对农村儿童教育获得的影响[J].中国农村观察,2016(3):53-63+96.

[196] 袁晓燕.众里寻他!?——一个基于婚姻匹配理论的综述[J].南方经济,2017(02):87-101.

[197] 曾福生,郭珍.不完全市场与农业发展方式的转变[J].农村经济,2012,(05):16-19.

[198] 曾雯露.零零后初中辍学青年研究——基于对粤北某农村零零后辍学青年的深度访谈[J].中国青年研究,2021(03):21-27.

[199] 曾毅,吴德清.八十年代以来我国离婚水平与年龄分布的变动趋势[J].中国社会科学,1995(6):71-82.

[200] 张川川,李雅娴,胡志安.社会养老保险、养老预期和出生人口性别比[J].经济学(季刊),2017,16(02):749-770.

[201] 张川川,马光荣.宗族文化、男孩偏好与女性发展[J].世界经济,2017,40(03):122-143.

[202] 张川川,陶美娟.性别比失衡、婚姻支付与代际支持[J].经济科学,2020,(02):87-100.

[203] 张立平,樊平.传统农业地区的婚姻特征——山东省陵县调查[J].社会学研究,1993,(5):92-100.

[204] 张希坡.中国婚姻立法史[M].北京:人民出版社,2004.

[205] 张雪霖.阶层分化、社会流动和农村离婚新秩序——以鲁西北C村离婚经验为例[J].中国青年研究,2016,(12):33-38+110.

[206] 中国社会科学院语言研究所词典室. 现代汉语词典,第6版[M].北京:商务印书馆,2005.

[207] 周皓,李丁.我国不同省份通婚圈概况及其历史变化——将人口学引入通婚圈的研究[J].开放时代, 2009(07): 100-115.

[208] 周丽娜,王忠武.值得关注的农村通婚圈缩小现象[J].新疆社会科学,2006(05):105-108.

[209] 周心怡,邓龙真,龚锋.人口老龄化、养老保险缴费率与基本养老金目标替代率[J].财贸研究,2020(2):57-67.

中图分类号:

 F32    

开放日期:

 2023-12-08    

无标题文档

   建议浏览器: 谷歌 火狐 360请用极速模式,双核浏览器请用极速模式